Approval Voting in Product Societies
- Published in 2017
- Added on
In the collection
In approval voting, individuals vote for all platforms that they find acceptable. In this situation it is natural to ask: When is agreement possible? What conditions guarantee that some fraction of the voters agree on even a single platform? Berg et. al. found such conditions when voters are asked to make a decision on a single issue that can be represented on a linear spectrum. In particular, they showed that if two out of every three voters agree on a platform, there is a platform that is acceptable to a majority of the voters. Hardin developed an analogous result when the issue can be represented on a circular spectrum. We examine scenarios in which voters must make two decisions simultaneously. For example, if voters must decide on the day of the week to hold a meeting and the length of the meeting, then the space of possible options forms a cylindrical spectrum. Previous results do not apply to these multi-dimensional voting societies because a voter's preference on one issue often impacts their preference on another. We present a general lower bound on agreement in a two-dimensional voting society, and then examine specific results for societies whose spectra are cylinders and tori.
Links
Other information
- key
- ApprovalVotinginProductSocieties
- type
- article
- date_added
- 2017-03-30
- date_published
- 2017-10-09
BibTeX entry
@article{ApprovalVotinginProductSocieties, key = {ApprovalVotinginProductSocieties}, type = {article}, title = {Approval Voting in Product Societies}, author = {Kristen Mazur and Mutiara Sondjaja and Matthew Wright and Carolyn Yarnall}, abstract = {In approval voting, individuals vote for all platforms that they find acceptable. In this situation it is natural to ask: When is agreement possible? What conditions guarantee that some fraction of the voters agree on even a single platform? Berg et. al. found such conditions when voters are asked to make a decision on a single issue that can be represented on a linear spectrum. In particular, they showed that if two out of every three voters agree on a platform, there is a platform that is acceptable to a majority of the voters. Hardin developed an analogous result when the issue can be represented on a circular spectrum. We examine scenarios in which voters must make two decisions simultaneously. For example, if voters must decide on the day of the week to hold a meeting and the length of the meeting, then the space of possible options forms a cylindrical spectrum. Previous results do not apply to these multi-dimensional voting societies because a voter's preference on one issue often impacts their preference on another. We present a general lower bound on agreement in a two-dimensional voting society, and then examine specific results for societies whose spectra are cylinders and tori.}, comment = {}, date_added = {2017-03-30}, date_published = {2017-10-09}, urls = {http://arxiv.org/abs/1703.09870v1,http://arxiv.org/pdf/1703.09870v1}, collections = {Protocols and strategies}, url = {http://arxiv.org/abs/1703.09870v1 http://arxiv.org/pdf/1703.09870v1}, urldate = {2017-03-30}, archivePrefix = {arXiv}, eprint = {1703.09870}, primaryClass = {math.CO}, year = 2017 }